This book, by Keith Tribe, explores themes and topics in the linguistic history of economics. I'm barely gonna write anything here as I already wrote a full review of it for the Rethinking Economics opinion blog (link below). It was a pretty sloggish read, but interesting in an academic sort of way; if you like economics, historical methodology, and the complexities of changeable language use in century-spanning contexts, then this book is right up your street.
HERE'S THE FULL REVIEW I DID
[Edit November 2016: it appears that during a recent re-vamp of Rethinking Economics' website, the entire blog has been lost into the Error 404 ether - so pasted below is my review's text.]
[Edit November 2016: it appears that during a recent re-vamp of Rethinking Economics' website, the entire blog has been lost into the Error 404 ether - so pasted below is my review's text.]
History is the art
of constructing causal narratives between past events and holding them up for
analysis. The history of economics – how it has been gradually built up and
developed as a field of study over centuries – follows the same rule:
historians studying the history of economics have to throw themselves fully
into the heads of long-dead economists to try to perceive who or what
influenced them, how, why, and to what effect on other deceased thinkers.
Unfortunately, since both normal historical events and
the economists studied by one studying the history of economics are, by
definition, history – we run into the usual gamut of difficulties ascertaining
exactly how a particular event happened, or exactly what a particular economist
thought and why. The historiographical issues of correctly sourcing and interpreting texts are
predictably smaller for tracing the history of an academic discipline than they
are for tracing actual history, but by no means has this seen historians of
economics refrain entirely from making unwarranted leaps of assertion.
Keith Tribe’s book has this complex criticism running
throughout. He takes a philological approach; closely scrutinising the
language used in canonical texts of economic history to determine exactly what
they originally meant. With immensely wide scholarship, he lays out the
academic biographies, cultural contexts, and influencing factors on each writer
he tackles, to lay the outputs of his philological analysis in an intelligible
framework.
The book’s content is in three parts. Firstly, a
discussion of the word ‘economy’. It does not mean the same thing to us as it
would have meant to an Ancient Greek or Adam Smith, and thus any historian of
economics peering at older uses must revise what they understand the writer to
mean. In this opening chapter, he draws out the evolution of the word’s
definition from Aristotle to the 20th century, followed by an
overview of how rough measures for this final concept of ‘economy’ (i.e.
national income, or GDP) came to be numerically constructed. Secondly, he turns
to Adam Smith, dissecting with indefatigable precision the historical
influences and writings of the Scottish original economist, to show an internal
consistency in Smithian arguments about trade in The Wealth of Nations; he also tackles ‘das Adam Smith problem’,
the disjoint between selfishness-driven markets apparently espoused by Smith in
his economic work, and the altruism-driven social harmonies at the heart of Smith’s
Theory of Moral Sentiments, his prior
treatise in moral philosophy. In the third section, he analyses the work of
Karl Marx and Léon Walras, economists whose ideas seem almost wildly opposing
given that aspects of their influence have led on the one hand to Communism and
on the other to neoclassical apologists for free-market capitalism; but under
close historical scrutiny, both of them derive their core understanding of
society in a very similar way, from French political economists in an emergent
industrial context.
This content, separated from the main motor of the book
which is the philological approach discussed above, would be exceedingly dry
and there probably wouldn’t be much point reading it. But because Tribe has so
effectively cracked open our awareness of how texts, economists, and language, are
situated in historical circumstance, each section proves thoroughly insightful.
As a book more about the historiography of economics than about its history, it
serves as a refreshing and probably-much-needed rebuke to lazy modern
historians who might see the word ‘labour’ in an 1848 article and read into it
all their own 2015 assumptions and connotations about what that word implies
and derives from. We need instead, when reading old texts, to make the effort
of learning historical contexts, following linguistic usage roots back far
enough to see where they split, understanding the processes of individual
thought enough to recognise and respect them in a figure who we can only access
by reading their writings. Adam Smith, Karl Marx, Léon Walras, and the dozens
of other significant economists discussed in this book, did not produce their
ideas in a vacuum alone with only a rough sketch of modern economic theories.
That’s not how intellectual progress works. Thinkers’ contemporary settings,
things that they read and people they spoke to and socio-political events that
befell them, are of enormous importance and it is crucial that we have an acute
sensitivity to these when attempting to do history of any kind, including
economics. Likewise, the ability to properly grapple with words as historical
entities is vital; and this entails sometimes making the imaginative leap into
obsolete definitions so that we and whoever we’re reading are on the same page.
Language is not constant, nor is economic theory, and the failure to appreciate
this pair of stark facts will make a bad historian embarrass himself. Keith
Tribe has done great work here in showing how essential to understanding the
history of economics a philological approach is. He sheds small patches of
light on several topics, but more importantly, demonstrates how hard it
actually is to pin down definite knowledge if one is being sloppy. It is truly
masterful scholarship.
The book’s point is also, I think, an important one for
the Rethinking Economics movement.
Philological analysis of texts yields dense crossovers of influence and
discipline – if there is solid historical evidence that Marxian and Walrasian
economics derive from the same set of sources, then no conflicting theories
should be beyond critical discussion of where they may both be overlappingly
right. Also, the methodological approach to language and texts would be a
useful one for economics students to learn; admittedly, it’s one that ends up with
us being less easily able to know things, but much surer that we’re right when
we do. Economics degrees seldom encourage strong verbal reasoning or perceptive reading, but these are skills we do need.
For any reader interested in the history of economics, I
would recommend this; compared to most other texts in the field it treats less
of theoretical developments and individual economists’ projects, but for its overall point, widening
the scope of how we do (or should do) history, it is an indispensable addition.
No comments:
Post a Comment